Think Bigger About Remote Work

ogc163

Superstar
Joined
May 25, 2012
Messages
9,027
Reputation
2,150
Daps
22,319
Reppin
Bronx, NYC
A guest post by Adam Ozimek

I’ve written — and I still believe — that the rise of remote work triggered by the Covid pandemic will end up changing the way we produce things in the modern world. It has the potential to do for white-collar industries what electricity did for factory jobs — to distribute production to less costly places and allow more flexibility in job tasks. But for any of this to happen, remote work has to actually live up to the hype in terms of adoption.

So I asked my friend Adam Ozimek to write about the future of remote work, since he’s done plenty of research on the subject. Adam is the chief economist at the Economic Innovation group (a think tank whose founder I interviewed a year ago). Before that, he was an economist at Moody’s Analytics. He also co-wrote the popular econ blog Modeled Behavior, with Karl Smith. He tweets at @modeledbehavior.



The debate over remote work is evolving. We have gone from arguing about whether a significant level of remote working will be a permanent feature of the labor market to a greater focus on what the implications of that will be. Yet throughout this 2+ year debate, I think we have been consistently too pessimistic.

There are two reasons for more optimism. First, the thinking about who remote work is “leaving behind.” is far too narrow. Second, remote work opens up new frontiers for innovation and improved economic geography, and should spur bigger thinking by policymakers, pundits, and businesses, and more.

Before I begin making the case for why we should be more optimistic about remote work, we must first dig into what exactly it seems that remote work is doing so far.

Remote work and inequality

Let’s start first with who remote work is directly benefiting, and who it is directly leaving behind. It is clear that not everyone can work remotely, and that working remotely is more common among the higher educated. Over the first year of the pandemic, 50 percent of those with a graduate degree were mostly working from home compared to only 10 percent of those with less with a high school degree. The education bias of remote work is consistent with pre-pandemic remote work patterns, and even which jobs can be done remotely in theory based on occupational characteristics.

In short, those with less education have less access to remote work jobs. The ability to work remotely is valued highly by some, with more than half of workers both saying that they place monetary value on it and also threatening to quit if forced back in the office. For those who value this way of working, working remotely represents a new direct benefit to higher skilled workers. Of course, for others who prefer to be in the office but are in an occupation where being fully remote proves optimal for firms, this will be a cost. But as a first approximation, I think this aspect of remote work does by itself increase inequality of outcomes.

Spillovers from urban exodus

Another source of concern is that remote work has driven an exodus of people out of large urban areas, and this will leave urban service-sector workers worse off. It certainly seems true at this point that remote work has driven an exodus from large urban areas. There are really two reasons this is happening.

First, remote work pushed people out of city centers into nearby suburbs, exurbs, and rural areas within the same metro area. This is what Bloom and Ramani call “the donut effect, and quite a few papers have shown evidence of it at this point. For example Gupta, Mittal, and Peeters use Zip Code level data to show that being farther from a city center has become less negative for prices and rents post pandemic (shown below).


Second, it is not just that people are changing where they are living within MSAs, but also moving out of big expensive MSAs entirely. You can see this clearly below in house price data from Zillow at the zipcode level from a recent paper of mine, with a “donut effect” that extends not just within the NYC metro area, but well into northeastern Pennsylvania and southern New Jersey. Looking at population data, Frey also showed that large urban metros have seen significant declines in population while non-metro areas have boomed.


So, yes, we have seen an urban exodus, both within metro areas and between them. But is remote work to blame? In a recent paper, I used regression analysis to see which factors best explain the change in county level population growth, comparing 2021 to pre-pandemic. I found bigger population losses in large urban areas with lots of occupations that could be done remotely, high housing costs, and where a large share of workers used to commute in. High housing costs and a supply of potential work-from-home jobs actually exacerbated each other, which is exactly what would be expected from remote work reducing the value of access to large, urban labor markets, and is consistent with remote work being an important demographic driver. (In technical terms, the interaction effect was significant, negative, and economically meaningful.)


Isn’t this bad news?

What does the urban exodus mean for those economies? Barrero, Bloom, and Davis estimate that workers spending less time at the office will reduce expenditures in major city centers by 5 to 10 percent. And that doesn’t even include the decline in spending from people moving away from urban areas. That combination sounds like it will be bad news for service-sector workers in those areas. When combined with the direct inequality of remote work opportunity, it is easy to paint a pessimistic picture altogether. However, we have to widen our lens and look more broadly.

The declining value of big city living

Something that is missed in this debate is that when remote workers (and their spending) reallocate themselves out of large urban areas, that creates new demand and new opportunities for service-sector workers in the places they move to. There is no reason to think that total spending will go down from remote work. Money saved from fewer lunches near the office will be spent on lunches or groceries closer to home. Yes, we should see retail and service sector demand decrease in urban cores and large urban areas like San Francisco and New York, but expand elsewhere.

This change should cause service workers to gradually follow the shifts in demand created by the new economic geography of remote work. One retort is that this will push lower skilled workers out of large urban areas, and this will be costly to them and leave them worse off. However, a growing body of evidence suggests that low-skilled workers in these places have been getting a bum deal over time anyway in terms of the economic return to living in superstar cities.

This story runs contrary to a lot of conventional wisdom, so it is worth digging into. It is true that one of the most important facts of economic geography used to be that lower skilled workers benefited from living in large urban areas where they could be surrounded by spillovers from more skilled workers. This theory was the crux of Moretti’s book The New Geography of Jobs. However, the evidence is accumulating that this spillover has changed over time.

Research from Autor first showed that while the high-skilled wage premium has continued to climb in more dense places, it has fallen for less skilled workers. This is what he calls “the falling ladder of urban opportunity.” But it’s even worse than it seems. Not only is the wage premium falling, but Card, Rothstein, and Yi argue that a significant share of the urban wage premium is due to those with unmeasured skills clustering there. So the wage premium is less than we thought, and it is also more due to worker sorting than actual increases in pay and productivity caused by the dense urban economy.

And folks, I hate to say it, but the story gets even worse from there. Because not only are low-skilled workers getting less of a pay bump than they used to, but urban NIMBYism means their housing expenses and cost of living have gone up significantly. Hoxie, Shoag, and Veuger go so far as to argue that once housing costs are taken into consideration, there is now an urban wage penalty for non-college workers. It’s not just housing either. Combining bank transaction data, scanner data, and much else, Moretti and Diamond look at broader consumption and find that expensive cities lead to less real consumption for less educated workers. While college-educated workers in expensive places earn a pay premium that is high enough to offset higher cost of living, the same is not true for low-skilled residents. Combining income and consumption effects, their results imply a high school dropout would experience a 26.9 percent increase in consumption from moving from the least to the most affordable commuting zone.

These stark results are a contrast to what was believed even a few years ago and also call into question whether consumer demand reallocation out of expensive cities is going to end up leaving workers worse off. In his work, Autor goes so far as to suggest exploring policies that “encouraging adults to seek work outside of those urban labor markets where the quality of jobs has not kept pace with the cost of living.” Remote work does exactly that, both for remote workers themselves but for those whose jobs their consumption supports.

In addition, the net costs to cities themselves should include positive impacts of greater competition. Many large cities have simply decided they don’t need to build enough housing, and have left affordability so poor and government services so unsatisfying that residents who no longer have to live there are rushing for the door. More competition is a good thing in the long-run, and residents and businesses feeling locked in by labor market access is not a recipe for good governance.

 

ogc163

Superstar
Joined
May 25, 2012
Messages
9,027
Reputation
2,150
Daps
22,319
Reppin
Bronx, NYC

Think bigger

There is also so much more to remote work than simply what I’ve discussed so far. Let me throw out a few things that I think are being totally underestimated by pessimists who would rather focus on direct effects and adjustment costs.

1. New places to live

In the olden times, way back in 2019, there was a major impediment to creating new places that weren’t in the immediate geographical vicinity of existing places: to lure in new workers, you needed new employers, but to lure in employers, you needed workers. This symbiosis becomes especially acute when talking about skilled, tradeable work where you couldn’t bootstrap labor demand by, for example, creating a single large tourism draw.

Remote work solves this chicken-and-egg problem. You can now create brand new places, far from existing labor markets, and lure in skilled remote workers with nice amenities.

I think the discussion around remote work is really behind this new reality. Yes, there has been some discussion of creating new cities in the U.S., for example from former Walmart CEO Marc Lore. However, while remote work does make creating new mega cities easier, and I hope that it happens, a mega city is still a massive and uncertain project. In contrast, new villages, towns, and small cities have become way easier and are subject to far less challenges of scale and uncertainty.

The creation of new places and new forms of places would be consistent with history. As Glaeser has written, transportation innovations have had enormous power shaping cities throughout history, influencing both their location and their form. Over and over, urban spaces have been built or rebuilt around new transportation technologies and the networks they create. Water-born mobility drove the location of most pre-modern cities; rail networks privileged areas with productive land and low density; subways and elevators allowed cities to expand horizontally and vertically; and, finally, the automobile has reshaped economic geography in more ways than we can count.

Remote work is in many ways similar to transportation technology. It is a way for employers and employees to work over vast distances with low cost. The above data shows that this is already affecting where people live, but for the most part we have not begun to see location and form of places that we live evolve.

My hope is that the next decade will lead property developers, planners, and investors to create brand new remote-worker villages and new places aimed at remote workers in locations previously untenable, all with amenities and forms that are as new and exciting as the changes past transportation innovations have ushered in. For example, the advent of retirement communities like the Villages did not simply replicate typical housing developments, but ushered in new development forms. What is the residential form that remote workers will demand? What amenities should these communities include? We need more bold thinking here.

2. New technologies

Remote working has gone far better than most expected, but the reality is we are still using pre-pandemic technologies for the mostpart. However, remote work patents have surged and new innovations in how we work together remotely are clearly underway. What this heralds remains to be seen, maybe virtual or augmented reality, maybe it just becomes easier to cross-talk on Zoom. Either way, however well remote work is going now, it is only going to get better.


3. New companies

Contrary to expectations, new business formation has surged post-pandemic. Part of this is due to the surge of independent work on online platforms. However, only some of this is businesses with planned employees. Just under one-third of business applications filed in the first three months of 2022 were for so-called high-propensity businesses likely to hire employees once operational. One driver, I believe, is that remote work is a general purpose technology. Like the steam engine or electrification, there will be wide impacts and spillovers through a variety of industries, and not all of them will be direct and obvious. Consider for example, how electrification allowed electrical lighting, elevators, and fans, which enabled creation of large multi-story department stores that transformed retail.

Likewise, we should expect remote work to create a variety of downstream spillovers, many of which we aren’t anticipating. It is easy to see why ways of working and new technologies privilege new firms who are starting from scratch, rather than existing firms who have to adapt business practices and even their pool of workers.

New businesses forming and utilizing new innovations should be a very positive thing for productivity growth, but if only we will see these changes as opportunities to take advantage of rather than change to fear.

More optimism is needed

Like almost all technologies, remote work will surely include significant adjustment costs and winners and losers. It’s prudent to think about both benefits and costs of remote work, both to help us anticipate them and to decide whether policy responses are necessary. Likewise, we should consider the inequality aspects as well.

However, what we should not do is succumb to a myopic pessimism that focuses on the direct costs and not on the wider benefits and potential of remote work. There is too much near-term, short-run, pessimistic thinking. Even those who are thinking boldly tend towards the negative, with predictions about the end of cities. I have seen this not just among pundits and economists, but business people in the private sector as well. I think there is ample case to look towards remote work with optimism and excitement.

Bigger thinking is needed. If we are too pessimistic, and continue the trend from the past few decades of declining dynamism rather than take advantage of the new momentum unlocked by remote work, we may fail to capture the profound benefits that are possible. For example, remote work allows the possibility of new places, but only if state and local NIMBYs do not block them. Likewise entrepreneurs will be able to utilize the advantages remote work gives them against bigger, slower incumbents, but only if they aren’t blocked by non-competes and other factors that have held back entrepreneurship in recent decades. Remote work provides the fuel for dynamism, but many blockers remain in place. The question whether society gets the full benefits of remote work in significant part comes down to whether policymakers stand in the way of the possibilities that are opening up.

 

hashmander

Hale End
Supporter
Joined
Jan 17, 2013
Messages
19,250
Reputation
4,623
Daps
82,242
Reppin
The Arsenal
What concerns me about remote working is it can actually work against Americans. A time will come when companies will start hiring cheaper workers overseas to work these jobs remotely.
yup i said as much at the start of this pandemic in one of these threads that H1-B visa aren't even gonna be needed as much because they'll just hire them to stay in their country instead of going through all that hassle of bringing them over here and paying payroll taxes, health insurance, etc. they'll pay for a starlink satellite and the service and think they're coming off light.
 

OperationNumbNutts

Superstar
Joined
Mar 11, 2022
Messages
6,721
Reputation
704
Daps
19,323
yup i said as much at the start of this pandemic in one of these threads that H1-B visa aren't even gonna be needed as much because they'll just hire them to stay in their country instead of going through all that hassle of bringing them over here and paying payroll taxes, health insurance, etc. they'll pay for a starlink satellite and the service and think they're coming off light.
Personally I didn't think of it from that angle but I agree. I hope it doesn't but I think it's going to eventually. If we do go into a full recession it will make companies think about it quicker.
 

JLova

Veteran
Supporter
Joined
May 6, 2012
Messages
59,033
Reputation
4,362
Daps
178,042
What concerns me about remote working is it can actually work against Americans. A time will come when companies will start hiring cheaper workers overseas to work these jobs remotely.
Already seeing a lot of American companies hiring in Canada. They’re able to pay Canadians more but still less than they pay American workers. How does this help Americans, though?

Before you had to apply for a visa and a bunch of other shyt. Now you don’t. I’ve never seen this many American companies hiring Canadians. This forces Canadian companies to pay more to compete. They been underpaying us for ages…that will change.
 

No1

Retired.
Supporter
Joined
Apr 30, 2012
Messages
30,507
Reputation
4,838
Daps
68,241
yup i said as much at the start of this pandemic in one of these threads that H1-B visa aren't even gonna be needed as much because they'll just hire them to stay in their country instead of going through all that hassle of bringing them over here and paying payroll taxes, health insurance, etc. they'll pay for a starlink satellite and the service and think they're coming off light.
There are many jobs that cannot be done by someone overseas and foreign jurisdictions often have even tougher employment laws. And you’re assuming states won’t pass laws to protect domestic workers the same way they do for freelance workers. There’s 0 chance NYC and SF won’t move to classify those people as New York or bay area employees for the purposes of employment law.
 

JLova

Veteran
Supporter
Joined
May 6, 2012
Messages
59,033
Reputation
4,362
Daps
178,042
There are many jobs that cannot be done by someone overseas and foreign jurisdictions often have even tougher employment laws. And you’re assuming states won’t pass laws to protect domestic workers the same way they do for freelance workers. There’s 0 chance NYC and SF won’t move to classify those people as New York or bay area employees for the purposes of employment law.

This. The US treats employees like garbage. Employees have 0 protection. However in Canada and the UK there is much better protection. American companies laying people off on a whim with years of service and offering no severance and insurance that ends in a week. You’d never see that in Canada.
 

hashmander

Hale End
Supporter
Joined
Jan 17, 2013
Messages
19,250
Reputation
4,623
Daps
82,242
Reppin
The Arsenal
well i was thinking more of a country like india when i mentioned H1-B visas since they get like 75% of them.
 

No1

Retired.
Supporter
Joined
Apr 30, 2012
Messages
30,507
Reputation
4,838
Daps
68,241
well i was thinking more of a country like india when i mentioned H1-B visas since they get like 75% of them.
I mean, if those companies can do that, they will already do it any way. I don’t see how remote work effects that.
 

GnauzBookOfRhymes

Superstar
Joined
May 7, 2012
Messages
12,499
Reputation
2,832
Daps
47,887
Reppin
NULL
True but I think slowly. I think it'll accelerate when it becomes a trend. Sort of like manufacturing jobs in the 80s.

Honestly I think people are going to be surprised at the extent to which the US is going to start retrenching when it comes to international trade. Even the GOP is now trying to refashion itself as "economic nationalists." The pandemic + supply chain vulnerabilities has already led to massive new investments in domestic things like chip manufacturing.
 

OperationNumbNutts

Superstar
Joined
Mar 11, 2022
Messages
6,721
Reputation
704
Daps
19,323
Honestly I think people are going to be surprised at the extent to which the US is going to start retrenching when it comes to international trade. Even the GOP is now trying to refashion itself as "economic nationalists." The pandemic + supply chain vulnerabilities has already led to massive new investments in domestic things like chip manufacturing.
Economic nationalists. :jbhmm: Curious where did you hear that?
 
Top